The Role
of Local Communities and Markets
in Pollution Control
by David
Wheeler with Shakeb Afsah and Benoit Laplante
Shakeb Afsah and Benoit Laplante are
consultants and David Wheeler is principal economist in the
Environment, Infrastructure, and Agriculture Division of the World
Bank s Policy Research Department. |
Factories in developing countries exhibit great variety in
environmental performance, despite the widely acknowledged weaknesses of
their regulatory systems. Even in the poorest countries, some plants
would satisfy OECD (Organization for Economic Commission and
Development) emissions standards. World Bank researchers are currently
investigating this phenomenon in several developing countries. Their
evidence suggests that neighboring communities and market forces
significantly affect factories environmental performance, even where
formal regulation does not exist.
In countries as different as China, Brazil, Mexico, and Indonesia,
communities that are richer, better educated, and more organized find
many ways of enforcing environmental norms for neighboring factories.
Where formal regulators are present, communities use the political
process to influence the tightness of enforcement. Where formal
regulators are absent or ineffective, community groups or
nongovernmental organizations may implement a kind of informal
regulation. The agents of informal regulation local religious
institutions, social organizations, community leaders, citizens
movements, or politicians vary from country to country, but the pattern
is similar: factories negotiate directly with local communities,
responding to social norms and/or explicit or implicit threats of
social, political, or physical sanctions if they fail to reduce the
damages caused by their emissions.
 |
Neighboring communities and market forces
can affect a factory's environmental performance
in tandem with regulations or in the absence
of regulation |
Market forces also seem powerful under some
conditions. Evidence from both OECD and developing countries suggests
that environmental reputation matters for firms whose expected costs or
revenues are affected by customer, supplier, and stockholder judgments
of firms environmental performance. For companies sensitive to
maintaining a good reputation, public recognition of good or bad
performance may over time translate to large expected gains or losses.
Two recent World Bank studies provide good illustrations of these
forces at work. The first study, an analysis of China s noncompliance
fee (or levy) for water polluters, highlights the effect of local
conditions on the actual enforcement practices of regulatory agencies.
The analysis identifies two sets of local factors that affect provincial
variations in enforcement of the levy. The first, reflecting the
principles of environmental economics, is local valuation of pollution
damage. This has three components: total pollution load, size of exposed
population, and local income. The second is community capacity to
understand and act on local environmental problems, indexed by measures
of information, education, and bargaining power. (Hettige, M., M.
Singh, S. Pargal and D. Wheeler. 1995. Patterns in Pollution Intensity:
Formal and Informal Regulation of Industrial Pollution in the U.S. and
Indonesia. Presented at the Annual Meeting, American Economic
Association, January, Washington, D.C. Laplante, B. and D. Wheeler.
1994. The Market Response to Environmental Incidents in Canada: A
Theoretical and Empirical Analysis. Southern Economic Journal 60(3):
657-672.) The results suggest an interesting interpretation of
Chinese pollution control policy. Lacking the appropriate information
for determining optimal pollution levels in each province, the national
government sets the official pollution levy at a reference level and
lets officials in each province trade off the costs and benefits of
effective implementation. By implication, the uniform implementation of
national standards and/or levy rates is not optimal; local conditions
determine what these should be.
In the second study, World Bank staff members have recently
participated in the design and evaluation of Indonesia s Program for
Pollution Control, Evaluation, and Rating (PROPER), which entails public
disclosure of environmental performance ratings for factories. In
PROPER, a polluter is assigned a color rating based on BAPEDAL s
(Indonesia s environmental agency) evaluation of its environmental
performance. A blue rating is given to factories that comply with
national regulatory standards, gold is reserved for world-class
performers, and black for factories that have made no attempt to control
pollution and are causing serious damage. Intermediate ratings are red
for factories that have some pollution control but fall short of
compliance and green for factories whose emissions control and
housekeeping procedures significantly exceed those needed for
compliance.
Why should PROPER have a significant impact on pollution? First,
although World Bank researchers have noted a pervasive pattern of
informal regulation or community influence on polluters behavior, Bank
findings also suggest that communities frequently need better
information about pollution sources and risks. In this context, public
disclosure offers significant empowerment. Armed with
government-certified performance ratings, communities are in a much
stronger position to negotiate pollution control agreements with
neighboring factories.
Second, from the market perspective, PROPER provides new incentives
for improved environmental performance. Under public disclosure,
external financing will be more difficult for firms whose poor pollution
record makes them risky investments. Conversely, gold and green firms
may well earn premiums in markets in which environmental reputation
matters. PROPER improves the regulators information by encouraging good
performers to identify themselves. It also provides competitive
incentives for superior performers to assist regulators in identifying
poor performers, because disclosure will penalize the latter.
PROPER s short-term impact has apparently been substantial. Many
plants rated red in the initial disclosure have attained blue status. Of
six plants initially rated black, five have already moved to red or blue
status, and the sixth has been brought to court by a neighboring
community. Although preliminary, these results suggest that industrial
polluters in developing countries respond to the incentives created by
public disclosure. This is good news for hard-pressed environmental
regulators, since PROPER-type programs represent a potentially potent,
low-cost enforcement tool.
PROPER:
Public Disclosure of Environmental Performance Ratings
A program garnering attention for possible replication in other
countries is Indonesia s Program for Pollution Control, Evaluation and
Rating (PROPER), launched in 1995.

After enlisting 200 volunteer industries, BAPEDAL
(Indonesia s environmental agency) collected self-reported pollution
data, assigned environmental performance ratings to each polluter,
reported results back to industry, and, after an interval to allow for
improvements,publicly announced the results with a color-coded grading
system. BAPEDAL then collected evidence suggesting that public ratings
had indeed reduced water pollution, chiefly through the cultural device
of shame avoidance and economic pressures, reinforced by conventional
enforcement and citizen lawsuits. The program now reaches 400 firms, and
the agency plans to enlist 1000 firms by the end of 1997 and include air
and hazardous waste pollution to its scope.
Community NGOs, the international community, government institutions,
and the general public rely on PROPER information to react accordingly.
The Indonesian Stock Exchange, for example, will not list any firms for
trading unless they have earned at least a blue rating.
The Philippines started a similar pilot program, entitled EcoWatch,
in late 1996 that includes many of the features of PROPER, but adds the
rating of municipal water and wastewater services. Mexico is also
considering the appropriateness of the PROPER model.
Back to the Table
of Contents |